scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

The changing face of mainstream economics

TLDR
The authors argue that economics is undergoing a fundamental shift in its method, away from neoclassical economics and into something new, which is centered on dynamics, recursive methods and complexity theory.
Abstract
This article argues that economics is currently undergoing a fundamental shift in its method, away from neoclassical economics and into something new. Although that something new has not been fully developed, it is beginning to take form and is centered on dynamics, recursive methods and complexity theory. The foundation of this change is coming from economists who are doing cutting edge work and influencing mainstream economics. These economists are defining and laying the theoretical groundwork for the fundamental shift that is occurring in the economics profession.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics
by
David Colander
Ric Holt
Barkley Rosser
November 2003
MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 03-27
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS
MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE
MIDDLEBURY, VERMONT 05753
http://www.middlebury.edu/~econ

The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics
David Colander, Ric Holt and Barkley Rosser
1. Introduction
If one reads the heterodox literature in economics these days, one gets the impression that
modern mainstream economics is much like the economics of 50 years ago; it is called
neoclassical economics and is criticized in much the same way that earlier heterodox economists
criticized the mainstream economics of the 1950s or 1960s. In this paper we argue that much of
this criticism today is off the mark because mainstream economic thinking has changed. We
argue that economics is moving away from a strict adherence to the holy trinity—rationality,
selfishness, and equilibrium—to a more eclectic position of purposeful behavior, enlightened
self-interest and sustainability. The paper develops our ideas by considering the nature of that
change and the process and sociological dynamics by which the profession changes.
2. The Profession as a Complex System
To understand our argument it is helpful to think of the profession as a complex system.
Complex systems cannot be understood from assumed first principles; they can only be
understood through the process of change that underlies them. In the same way, the economics
profession can best be understood by the process of change that characterizes it. Most
considerations of the economics profession have tended to take a static view of the profession,
which makes it seem as if it is an unchanging entity. That’s the approach that most heterodox
criticisms of the profession have taken. That's not the way we see the economics profession; we
see it as a dynamic entity, which generates a self-reproducing, evolving, complex system of
interacting ideas.
Getting a handle on such a dynamic entity and conveying its essence to others often
requires giving it static classifications and organizing it into distinct periods. Historians of
economic thought must do this to provide structure for their consideration of past economists.
But these classifications are crutches, not characterizations of reality. They are imposed by the
observer and are not necessarily part of the essence of the profession at any point in time. Any
static classification hides the dynamic change occurring underneath it. For this reason the
classifications used by historians of thought, such as Classical or Neoclassical, while useful and
perhaps even necessary, are nevertheless confining and miss important dimensions of the
profession.
3. The Edge of Economics
The changes in the profession are brought about by what we call work at the edge of
economics.
1
It is innovative and successful work at the edge of the profession that signals
1
The term, edge of economics, refers to work challenging the previously considered “orthodox” ideas.
Initially, we described it as cutting edge work, but some of our colleagues have pointed out that cutting

The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics
the future direction of change in economics and how the profession eventually comes to be
viewed and understood by its elite. The very concept of an edge of the profession is
designed to suggest a profession in which there are multiple views held within the
profession, and goes against the standard classifications of economics. Those standard
classifications convey a sense of the profession as a single set of ideas. In our view, that is
wrong; it is much more useful to characterize the economics profession as a diverse
evolving set of ideas, loosely held together by its modeling approach to economic
problems.
2
Standard classifications tend to miss the diversity that exists within the profession, and
the many new ideas that are being tried out. They miss the important insight that one can be part
of the mainstream and yet not necessarily hold “orthodox” ideas. Standard classifications also
emphasize a fairly narrow orthodox core of the profession and convey a picture of all
conventional economists accepting this core. The reality is more complicated; conventional
economists often hold a variety of views simultaneously. If the variance of views increases,
while the core remains relatively unchanged, the static characterization of the profession will not
change, but its dynamic characterization will.
A large variance in acceptable views, such as has emerged in the profession over recent
decades, signals that changes are likely in the future. In our view the interesting story in
economics over the past decades is the increasing variance of acceptable views, even though the
center of economics has not changed much. For example, mainstream economists today such as
William Baumol, George Akerlof, Thomas Schelling, Truman Bewley, and Paul Krugman, in
important aspects of their thinking, are working outside of what is generally considered the
orthodoxy of the profession. Yet, their ideas are widely accepted and discussed within the
mainstream of economics. It is such work that has increased the variance of acceptable views in
the profession.
To capture that variance of acceptable views, static classifications must be seen for what
they are—useful fictions that are meant for students and non-specialists. These classifications are
backward looking, and, to be meaningful, they must be supplemented with a discussion of the
variance of ideas acceptable to the mainstream. The reality is that at any point in time a
successful discipline will have hundreds of new ideas being tried out, as new methods, new
technology and new information become available. That is what happens at the edge of
economics.
This edge of economics has both intellectual and social elements. The intellectual aspect
of economics at the edge fundamentally involves originality. This does not mean that all ideas at
the edge are totally new. Ideas have origins, and grow better in some environments than in
others. The history of economics is full of instances in which old ideas are rehabilitated or
revived and found to be useful and advantageous within the new context that is emerging.
edge work can only be defined historically as work at the edge that has panned out. Comments by Larry
Moss, and Ken Koford were very helpful in redirecting us in our terminology.
2
Robert Solow (1996) writes “Today if you ask a mainstream economist a question about almost any
aspect of economic life, the response will be: suppose we model that situation and see what
happens…modern mainsteam economics consists of little else but examples of this process.”
2

The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics
In the work at the edge ideas, which previously have been considered central to
economics are being modified and broadened, and the process is changing the very nature of
economics. What is making it possible for these ideas to take root now, but not in the past, are
advances in analytic technology, such as non-linear dynamics, which has made it possible to
study much more complex models than before, developments in computing capabilities, which
have made studies with simulations and agent-based models much more useful, allowing
economists to study problems that do not have analytic solutions. Combined with advances in
other disciplines relevant to economics, which makes the integration among disciplines easier,
the combination of these advances has opened up completely new ways of integrating those ideas
into the core beliefs of the field, and has changed the core beliefs in important ways. For
example developments in nonlinear dynamics are now allowing alternative models of processes
that include sudden shifts from one equilibrium to another, and the development of agent-based
modeling is allowing researchers to explore models with heterogeneous agents and to move
away from a focus on unique equilibria.
4. Change within the Profession
Sociological issues impinge upon and constrain what is possible intellectually. The reproduction
of ideas involves the social, political, and economic structures of the academic and policymaking
establishments in which ideas are developed and transmitted. Ideas, however original and
possibly wonderful, that do not become accepted by some of the elite of the profession, and
which do not eventually get funded, will not be accepted and transmitted within the profession.
To internally move the discipline to a new position some of the profession's elite must accept
these ideas.
In our view what is occurring in economics today is a modification of the standard view
of paradigm shifts proposed by Thomas Kuhn (1970), at least as it relates to the economics
profession. Kuhn argued that the driving forces of change are those ideas that challenge the very
system of thought in a way that puts them outside the mainstream, and ultimately are only
introduced, "funeral by funeral" by a paradigm shift. This makes it easy to recognize that a
paradigm shift has occurred.
We see this view as not quite fitting the economics profession. From our dynamic
perspective an alternative channel exists that allows for significant changes to occur within the
mainstream of the profession. These changes do not lead to sudden paradigm shifts, but instead
lead to cumulative evolutionary changes that ultimately will be recognized as a revolutionary
change. The changes that lead to this ex-post revolution were initially accepted within the
profession gradually, more along the lines suggested by Imre Lakatos (1978). This alternative
channel is the following: When certain members of the existing elite become open to new ideas,
that openness allows new ideas to expand, develop, and integrate into the profession. In that case
change within the profession can be accepted gradually, being introduced "data set by data set"
and "new technique by new technique" as well as "funeral by funeral". In some cases these new
ideas will originate from outside the mainstream, from those who consider themselves heterodox,
even if the acceptance of such ideas leads to their “normalization” and removal from being
identified as heterodox.
3

The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics
These alternative channels allow the mainstream to expand and evolve to include a wider
range of approaches and understandings. Eventually, sufficient change is made so that future
historians of thought will consider the orthodoxy of the period changed. This, we believe, is
already occurring in economics. Mark Blaug, one of the most distinguished current historian of
economic thought, has pointed out that beginning as early as the 1950s the classification
"neoclassical economics" was no longer appropriate to characterize modern economics (1998,
p.2), an argument further developed by Colander (2000a).
The difference between Kuhn’s view and ours is in how changes generally come about in
a profession. We suggest that changes, even ones that will eventually be considered
revolutionary, often come from within and will not be noticed for years. Kuhn's view suggests
that they can only come from outside and are quite apparent when they occur. The dynamic
approach of change within the profession that we are introducing here involves stealth changes,
in which advocates of new ideas may gain acceptance among the elite of the profession and even
achieve positions of power and prominence within at least some leading academic institutions of
economics. The change, however, is so gradual that the profession often does not notice that the
change has occurred.
The reason for the difference is the multiple dimensionalities that we see in the
mainstream profession. It is a complex system of evolving ideas. Individuals in the profession
see minute changes upon minute change but do not have a perception of the aggregate of the
changes. Only when historians of thought look back, after sufficient time has passed to gain
some historical perspective, does the larger change become apparent.
5. The Process of Change
Both the social and intellectual aspects of change must be taken into account in order to
understand the evolution of ideas. The work at the edge is generally begun by younger
researchers and in some cases those who are doing heterodox work. But their ability to do that
work, and to have their work affect the profession, is dependent on the existence of crucial
persons in the leading academic establishments, representing the mainstream of economics, who
are open to seriously considering new ideas. These crucial people may be the ones who have
developed what was considered the old orthodoxy, but their having developed it doesn't mean
that they aren't open to change and new ideas. There is nothing inconsistent with being one of the
originators of a theory and simultaneously being a critic of that theory. Good economists
simultaneously recognize the strengths and limitations of a theory, and are open to new
approaches and ideas. A good example of a person that fits this category is Kenneth Arrow.
Although he is associated with what is considered modern neoclassical orthodoxy, he was
instrumental in the introduction of the complexity approach into economics.
3
The consideration and ultimate acceptance of a new idea by a certain portion of the elite
becomes a key to the process of how the conventional foundation of the discipline evolves. It is
not crucial that those developing the ideas initially be at leading establishments. But they must be
able to attract the attention of influential individuals at those institutions in order for their ideas
3
Mirowski (2002, pp. 432-436) argues that an important influence on Arrow in his change of view was a
former student, Alain Lewis (1985), whose work continues to be little known by most of the profession.
4

Citations
More filters
Journal Article

Value and Capital

TL;DR: In the last few years the situation has considerably changed and there is now a growing interest in Marxism, particularly among the younger social scientists of America as mentioned in this paper, and the book under review falls within this trend.
Journal ArticleDOI

"I think I can, I think I can": Overconfidence and entrepreneurial behavior

TL;DR: The authors found that subjective, and often biased, perceptions have a crucial impact on new business creation across all countries in their sample and that the strongest cross-national covariate of an individual's entrepreneurial propensity is whether the person believes herself to have the sufficient skills, knowledge, and ability to start a business.
Journal ArticleDOI

The nature of heterodox economics

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors argue that matters of ontology are central in distinguishing heterodoxy from the orthodoxy, and defend criteria other than varying commitments to specific substantive theories, policy measures or techniques of analysis.
Journal ArticleDOI

Happiness economics from 35,000 feet

TL;DR: The economics of happiness is an expanding field, with a growing number of applied papers reporting empirical associations between happiness and other variables as discussed by the authors, and a broad view of the topic, aiming to provide an outline of the literature in relation to happiness economics' origins, definitions, theory, methods, applications, critiques, relations with other areas of economic research, political and policy connections and promising directions for future inquiry.
References
More filters
Book

Theory of Self-Reproducing Automata

TL;DR: This invention relates to prefabricated buildings and comprises a central unit having a peripheral section therearound to form a main residential part defined by an assembly of juxtaposed roofing and facing trusses.
Journal ArticleDOI

Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory

TL;DR: In this article, a modification of economic analysis to incorporate incomplete information and uncertain foresight as axioms is suggested, which embodies the principles of biological evolution and natural selection by interpreting the economic system as an adoptive mechanism which chooses among exploratory actions generated by the adaptive pursuit of "success" or "profit".
Book ChapterDOI

Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a problem which has not heretofore been analysed and provide a theory to explain, under different circumstances, three related phenomena: (1) spendthriftiness; (2) the deliberate regimenting of one's future economic behaviour, even at a cost; and (3) thrift.
Book

Value and Capital

R. F. Harrod, +1 more
Book

Complexity: The Emerging Science at the Edge of Order and Chaos

TL;DR: In a rented convent in Santa Fe, a revolution has been brewing: Nobel Laureates in physics and economics such as Murray Gell-Mann and Kenneth Arrow, and pony-tailed graduate students, mathematicians, and computer scientists down from Los Alamos are gathering novel ideas about interconnectedness, coevolution, chaos, structure, and order and forging them into an entirely new, unified way of thinking about nature, human social behavior, life, and the universe itself.
Frequently Asked Questions (9)
Q1. What are the contributions in "The changing face of mainstream economics the future direction of change in economics and how" ?

This paper argue that mainstream economics is moving away from a strict adherence to the holy trinity ( rationality, selfishness, and equilibrium ) to a more eclectic position of purposeful behavior, enlightened self-interest and sustainability. 

Perhaps the most important characteristic of the neoclassical orthodoxy is that axiomatic deduction is the preferred methodological approach. 

3The consideration and ultimate acceptance of a new idea by a certain portion of the elite becomes a key to the process of how the conventional foundation of the discipline evolves. 

Since the average undergraduate professor has been out of graduate school for a long period of time, the average professor (which the textbooks target as their audience) will generally be most comfortable teaching older material as the core of the course, with new material scattered throughout. 

What is making it possible for these ideas to take root now, but not in the past, are advances in analytic technology, such as non-linear dynamics, which has made it possible to study much more complex models than before, developments in computing capabilities, which have made studies with simulations and agent-based models much more useful, allowing economists to study problems that do not have analytic solutions. 

it is because of their method, not their ideas, that most heterodox find themselves defined outside the field by the elite. 

The paper develops their ideas by considering the nature of that change and the process and sociological dynamics by which the profession changes. 

It is helpful in making their argument to carefully consider the terms, mainstream, orthodox, heterodox, how they are used, and how they relate to their idea that the dynamics of change in a profession is at the edge of the profession. 

In their view the interesting story in economics over the past decades is the increasing variance of acceptable views, even though the center of economics has not changed much.